The College
of Education at Michigan State University initiated a series of
education policy forums in October 1997. The series of five forums
are designed to deal with a range of educational issues of importance
and relevance to state policymakers. The first forum featured
the research of professors David
Plank and Gary
Sykes, both of whom teach in the Department of Educational
Administration. They discussed preliminary findings from two separate
studies they are conducting on charter schools and school choice.
The gave their talk on October 28, 1997.
David Plank
Id like to offer a few prefatory remarks and then
talk a little bit about the systemic effects of the introduction
of expanded opportunities for choice, and then Gary (Sykes) will
go on to talk about how choice might affect teaching and learning
in schools and classroom. At the outset, though, Id like
to just note that this is obviously an exciting but also highly
contentious issue and there are deeply held views and values on
both sides of the issue. Many of you in this room are both well
informed on choice policy and deeply committed to particular policy
positions, and we have therefore reserved a considerable amount
of time at the end of todays presentation for discussion
and debate. I think we as researchers have a great deal to learn
from that debate. I guess I would be more modest than President
McPherson. I think we have a great deal to learn from that debate
simply in learning to ask the right questions; much less in presenting
findings on the issue.
At this point, were going
to offer a range of informed speculations about some likely effects,
some likely consequences, of expanded choice in Michigans
educational system. Unfortunately, well be able to offer
relatively few solid findings for two reasons. The first reason
is that up to now, choice has had relatively few effects on Michigans
education system. Key actors in the system including both new
entrants to the system, whether those are directors of charter
schools or current actors in the system, including local superintendents
and school principals, are only now beginning to adapt their behavior
to a dramatically changed policy environment. The second reason
is that ours is a three-year study and were in the first
year of the study, so its really too early for us draw firm
conclusions from the data we have begun collecting. Id also
like to make it clear that we are neither advocates nor opponents
of choice. I think it would be fair to say that the two of us
started out in somewhat different positions with respect to the
virtues and disadvantages of choice, but we have come to a sort
of shared agnosticism about what choice is likely to bring to
Michigans education system. Our goal at the present time
is simply to track changes over time and to seek to understand
the likely effects of expanded choice opportunities for schools,
classrooms and students.
One final remark. There are two
questions that we are not asking, which we wont address
to today and which we are not asking in our studies. These have
to do with the achievement effects of choice, and second the stratification
effects of choice. Achievement effects as all of you know is a
profoundly vexed issue in traditional public schools, and more
so when one tries to compare across traditional public schools
and charter schools or choice schools. We simply got the data
or, in this particular set of studies, the capacity to look in
detail at those. And with respect to stratification effects, as
you know the data the state collects that would allow one to address
stratification effects are very limited at this point. There is
clearly a need for more information on those issues. If the data
were to become available we would certainly look at the questions.
But at the present time we have no useful information on those.
I am going to talk about four main
subjects. In the interest of time, I am going to focus on two
of those. The first point is that the big changes in Michigans
educational system over the past several years are really attributable
to Proposal A rather than the introduction of school choice. Were
still trying to work out the consequences of Proposal A, still
trying to figure what changes Proposal A has wrought in the system.
One of those changes was to make expanded opportunities of choice
possible, but to date the effects of choice and charter schools
on the system have been considerably smaller than the effects
that were brought about by Proposal A. The second point is that
choice, interdistrict choice and the introduction of charter schools
represent very different strategies for change and are likely
to have very different consequences. Both expand opportunities
for parents to make choices, but they effect the education system
in quite different ways. The third point is that the introduction
of markets or quasi-markets into the education system has to overcome
some very powerful sources of resistance if it is to bring about
significant change or improvement in the education that children
receive, and we dont have yet enough evidence that expanded
choice will prove to be a sufficiently powerful instrument to
address the most serious problems in the educational system. And
the final point that I will make is that the specific rules governing
schools and students matter decisively in evaluating the effects
of expanded opportunities for choice. Policies that Michigan has
adopted are quite different from the policies adopted in California
or in Connecticut, and therefore it is wise to be cautious in
attempting to draw general conclusions about the costs or benefits
of choice.
As I say, I am going to focus on
the middle two of those points. So with respect to Proposal A,
Ill just say two quick things. The first is that Proposal
A radically diminished the importance of school districts in Michigans
education system, and the power of local school boards. School
districts no longer have an independent revenue base, but instead
depend on the state for their funds, which greatly increases the
states leverage over local schools and school district.
Many of the policy issues that we think about and talk about on
a daily basis are attributable to the shift in power from the
local level to the state level: The issues of testing and assessment;
curriculum guidelines; the issues recently of the school calendar
and the opening day for schools; the issue of state takeovers
of failing schools or school districts. The second main consequence
of Proposal A was that it shifted the main determinant of school
districts revenues from local property wealth to student
numbers. The only way now that school districts can increase their
revenues is by increasing enrollments. In effect, the consequence
of that is that revenues belong to students rather than to school
districts, and that makes students subsidies portable in
a way that property wealth could never be portable. The ultimate
consequence of that is that when we introduced choice options
into the system, we made it possible to start charter schools
or made it possible for students to move among school districts;
that theoretical portability of state subsidies became real. It
became possible for parents to exercise their options as to where
to enroll their students. The fact that school districts no longer
own their students or the revenues that attach to them became
a reality. The consequence of that as a local superintendent here
in the Lansing area told me the other day is that every student
in the school system is a choice student whether theyve
moved out of their neighborhood school or not. Every student is
a choice student and has the option to change schools.
The second big point is the
differential effects of charter schools and interdistrict choice.
Having gotten my Ph.D. from the University of Chicago, I guess
it is a sort of flaw in my character but I think about these issues
as an economist thinks about them. And as a Chicago economist
thinks about them, which is a particularly bad way to do so, I
suppose. So Id like to talk a little about the market consequences
of the two kinds of reforms. As Ive thought about giving
this talk, Ive tried to identify some analogies as to what
weve done in the education system by introducing interdistrict
choice and charter schools.
One way to think about charter
schools is by analogy to the deregulation of other monopolies
in the public sector, specifically the monopolies previous enjoyed
by the post office and the telephone company. What weve
provided is permission for new competitors to enter a formally
protected market, but its an unusual market in education
in that competition in price is ruled out. The cost to parents
in the education system is effectively the same whether their
children attend traditional public schools or charter schools.
So new competitors in the system, i.e., the directors of charter
schools, can only succeed by offering a more attractive package
of services for the same price, and this raises two kinds of questions.
The first question is: How can charter schools be more efficient
than public schools so that they can provide more attractive services
without additional revenues? And the second questions is: What
kinds of services are they likely to offer to distinguish themselves
from traditional public schools? There are a variety of answers
to the first question. Some ways of accomplishing increased efficiency
in charter schools include shifting cost to parents. For example,
the cost of transportation or the cost of extracurricular activities.
This is an option that is available to administrators at public
schools as well, but, up to now at least, has been taken more
advantage of by charter schools. A second way to be more efficient
would be to pay lower salaries to teachers by either hiring younger
or less experienced teachers, or by keeping teacher unions out
of charter schools. There may also be some opportunity for economies
of scale in the provision of charter schools as operations such
as the Edison Project demonstrate, where the Edison Project aspires
at least to provide a single, standardized model of the curriculum
in schools across the country.
With respect to the second question,
I think there are two different kinds of competitors that are
likely to emerge in the market for public schools. The first of
these would be more focused and relatively small-scale producers
aiming at what you might call niche markets. These charter schools
respond to parents who explicitly dont want the standard
package of services provided in traditional public schools. For
example, African-centered schools in Detroit or here in Lansing,
or Armenian-centered schools in suburban Detroit, or in schools
that are oriented to other distinct value orientations. I was
struck the other day when reading about the Million Woman March
that one of the three demands that was consistently mentioned
in the news accounts of that march was separate schools for African-American
children. So it may be that the market for distinct value orientations
in education has not been exhausted at all. I also have a couple
of students who are very keen to start all-girl academies. They
havent taken active steps to do that yet, but I think there
is an active market there. Its essential to recognize that
these kinds of strategies aimed at niche markets are most likely
to be effective in urban districts where the demand for schooling
is highly diverse and where a single provider faces difficulties
in responding to the expectations of all constituencies. In suburban
areas, many and probably most have moved to the community to take
advantage of the education provided in the public school system,
and in rural areas the demand is simply too limited to support
a broad array of providers. So what we see are some small-scale
providers, both church schools and also often home schooling.
The second kind of alternative
that charter schools present is to provide some space for focused
and efficient production in head-to-head competition with traditional
public schools. The examples of this would be the Edison Project
and in the Michigan Education Development Corporation down in
southwest Michigan. I would argue that both these enterprises
are seeking to out do traditional public schools at their own
game by providing an attractive environment for parents that features
a safe, disciplined learning environment that focuses on the mastery
of basic skills, and the generally very traditional common curriculum.
In the case of Edison, at least, they also provided some additional
services to parents, including an extended day and extended year
and lap top computers which they sent home with parents. Thinking
about charter schools and what effects charter schools are likely
to have, we need to recognize that there are these diverse demands
for different kinds of education, that there is space for niche
marketing, for specialized producers in the education system.
It is also important to recognize that the kinds of challenges
that Edison and EDC represent are not niche marketing. Again,
if you think back to the analogy with the post office and telephone
company, these are not motorcycle messenger services or bulk mail
distributors, these are MCI and Sprint, who are trying to take
away the core customers of the previous monopoly. This is most
likely to emerge in urban areas, but it is not likely to be restricted
to urban areas over time.
With respect to interdistrict choice,
the big change that interdistrict choice brings about is to put
together formerly independent school districts into a single pool
of students. Where in the past a school district could count on
enrollment from its local student base, now the student base has
to be shared with neighboring school districts. This brings some
very new conditions for administrators in the public school system.
The important thing to recognize about interdistrict choice as
a strategy for bringing about change in the education system is
that interdistrict choice is genuinely and truly as zero-sum game.
The only matter that is at stake in the competition is market
share because the size of the market is fixed. Competition on
price is ruled by statute so that you cant offer discounts
to parents, and there is virtually no way to expand the market,
to bring in new customers because by law all children of school-going
age have to be in school. So there is no possibility to expand
the market. Having said that, Ill qualify it. The one way
in which they could expand the market would be to bring in students
from outside, which would mainly be from private schools. One
of the things weve observed here in Lansing, at least, is
that a substantial share of the parents who have taken advantage
of interdistrict choice have been formerly private school parents
who have moved back to the public system. But it is important
to note that, in thinking about expanding the market that success
in expanding the market, does not necessarily benefit the players
in the game and may, in fact, penalize them because the revenue
pool, at least in the short run, is also fixed. This means that
if new students enter the system, the per capita subsidy from
the state is reduced for all students.
From the point of view of school
administrators, choice represents both a threat and an opportunity
because it brings formerly independent school districts into strategic
interaction for really the first time. The exemplar case to think
about this is Mount Clemens, in Macomb County, where a couple
of years ago the superintendent spent $7,500 marketing an new
all-day kindergarten program, and enrolled 50 new students from
neighboring school districts at $7,000 a head. You can do the
math. Its not a bad rate of return. In the longer run, it
simply demonstrates the advantages of going first, of breaking
ranks and taking advantage of the opportunities that choice provides
because subsequent competitors necessarily, by definition, reap
smaller rewards and the total net reward is zero. So the most
important consequence of interdistrict choice as it works itself
out in the system is likely to be a further sorting of students
as parents choose the schools and school districts that provide
the array of services closest to what they want for their children.
This could be positive if schools
specialize in constructive ways. If schools or school districts
provide services that are particularly well adapted for particular
groups of students. But it can also be negative; either if parents
make choices on invidious criteria, including race, or as schools
attempt to shift away from providing services for high cost, difficult
to educate students, or to recruit especially desirable students.
An example of that would be promising student athletes. Encouraging
schools to specialize in working with high cost rather than low
cost students would almost certainly require additional state
subsidies to support the education of those children. Moreover,
positive effects from interdistrict choice would require diversification
on the supply side. In other words, in the kinds of education
services that local school districts provide. But there is little
evidence as to how this would occur and even less that it is occurring
except at the margins. There is some demand for African-centered
education, for alternative education, clearly an intense demand
for all-day kindergarten, which is clearly becoming the standard
in Michigans public schools. Potential markets for other
kinds of specialization, including arts academies, science academies,
international baccalaureate academies. But there are obstacles
to the implementation of these kinds of strategies. One is that
admission has to be according to lottery, which might undermine
the integrity of some programs. Moreover, traditional public school
districts capacity to offer specialized programs that attract
a specific clientele is often legally questionable. For example,
in the city of Lansing its not clear that the Lansing public
schools could offer African-center education because the likely
racial balance would depart rather dramatically from the racial
balance required by the court order.
I am going to talk a little
about the obstacles choice must overcome if its going to bring
about positive changes in Michigan schools. Two of those are especially
important. The first is that parents already have lots of choice
options. They have choices about where they are choosing to live,
choices about the public schools that their children attend, for
example in Lansing all of the schools in the Lansing public school
system are choice schools, and choices about the tracks, about
the curricula, about extracurricular activities that their children
engage in. Its not immediately clear that the addition of
charter schools and interdistrict choice sufficiently expands
the array of choices that parents already have to bring about
dramatic changes.
The other key obstacle is the extreme
turbulence of urban school districts, particularly the demographic
turbulence and the weak incentive effects of choice for schools
and teachers in existing school districts. Again, in the city
of Lansing we now have the data on student turnover in public
schools and most of the schools in the city. Twenty-five to 50
percent of the children will change schools over the course of
a single school year, and thats without taking into account
the opportunities that they have for changing school districts
or for attending charter schools. And just based on our interviews
with charter school principals it appears that the level of turbulence,
the levels of student turnover, are about the same for charter
schools as they are for public schools. So it is not clear that
adding new choice opportunities will send a clear message to educators
who are already dealing with sort of amazingly high levels of
student turnover in their schools. On the incentive side, the
incentive effects of choice are quite different in traditional
schools than in charter schools. In a district that I wont
name, if a school is successful in attracting an additional student
the school gets $69 additional dollars to pay of Xeroxing and
other services for the students. If a charter school in the same
district attracts that student, the charter receives $6,100, so
that the incentive effects are likely to be considerably more
powerful for charter schools than they are in traditional public
schools.
As I say, those are the two points
I want to emphasize. I will simply say at the end that the key
policy questions concern how the choice system is to be regulated.
It is clear to us at least that choice is here to stay, so the
debate is no longer about whether to allow parents to make choices
or not. But it is equally clear that choice is not a panacea despite
the claims of some of our academic colleagues. By itself, it will
not solve the most serious problems of Michigans education
system or any other education system. So the debate necessarily
revolves around questions of how the choice system should be designed
and what other complimentary education policies have to be in
place to insure that the consequences of choice are positive rather
than negative. I will stop there and pass it on to Gary.
Gary Sykes
Another kind of question we are pursuing in our work
asks: Will the introduction of choice policy affect what happens
inside of schools and classrooms? That is, would we believe that
the nature of teaching and learning in schools of choice and regular
public schools might change as a result of choice policy? Would
choice be a stimulus around the nature of instruction? Certainly,
at least some of the arguments in favor of choice have emphasized
that that will happen, and I would just make four observations
on that issue.
The first is that proponents of
choice claim that it will stimulate innovation and the spread
of good ideas or popular ideas and practices through processes
of entrepreneurialism, competition and imitation. That seems to
be a plausible point to make, but wed refine it somewhat
based on our observations to date by asking not whether this happens,
but in relation to what kinds of innovations. Our hunch is: Certain
kinds but not others.
In particular, our speculative
point, our hypothesis, is that the kinds of innovations that choice
policy is likely to stimulate are those that may be added on to
the existing structure and functioning of schools together with
those that are likely to attract a constituency. Examples would
be, as you have heard, all-day kindergarten, sending lap tops
home with children, having parent contracts for involvement. That
is, various kinds of innovations that dont penetrate to
the core operation of teaching and learning, but instead in some
sense may be added on to or mixed into the way schools have always
functions. The kinds of innovations that choice appears unlikely
to stimulate are those that require deep changes in the nature
of instructional practice as such changes implicate teacher knowledge
and skill, new norms, roles, and structures within classroom,
the introduction of new instructional materials, whose use requires
and places skill demands on teachers. All of those kinds of changes
are unlikely, we think, to be stimulated by the introduction of
choice.
But I think what is interesting
about that observation is that it perfectly reflects the history
of school reform in this country. That is to say, exactly that
generalization has been made by historians concerning those reforms
that have lasted in changing the American school system over its
180-year existence. In that sense then, choice operates as a stimulus
for reform at the level of fundamental teaching and learning in
about the same way that most other efforts have operated whether
those be changes in the curriculum or efforts to decentralized
or involve parents or incorporate progressive ideas about instruction
into schools. The reforms that have lasted in the evolution of
the American school system having been those that have been easy
to add on and that have attracted a political constituency around
them. An example would be special education, where the parents
of special needs students constitute a powerful constituency for
a set of reforms aimed at increasing resources for special needs
children. Choice will be good at stimulating some developments
within the schools, but not others. How one evaluates the impact
of choice on curriculum and instruction depends a great deal on
what you believe needs to change for improvements in learning
to occur, and we can talk a little about that because that will
provoke argument.
The second observation concerns
the ideas that influence curriculum and instruction and the sources
of influence on those ideas. Within the choice movement, parent
and community preferences appear to play a more prominent role
than professional judgments, and given the documented split between
popular and professional views about education, and now I am thinking
particularly about the surveys the Public Agenda group has made
that have shown that there are deep divisions within our society
between public and professional views of schooling. It appears
that popular view are likely to more prominent in choice and charter
schools. Roughly this translates to a tendency in schools of choice
toward more traditional approaches to teaching and learning that
might be expressed concretely in such things as phonics-based
approaches to literacy, more traditional approaches to mathematics
rather than the avant garde NCTM mathematics standards, more traditional
approaches to the teaching science rather the so-called constructivist
approaches. That is to say, choice is likely to stimulate an instructional
regime in schools that is traditional because that accords more
closely to the preferences of parents and communities to what
they want to see going on in terms of teaching and learning in
classrooms.
At the same time, it also appears
that charters and choice give expanded scope for particular and
specialized approaches to instruction and to curriculum that are
culturally tuned to societal subgroups, that seek schools representing
their particular approaches. Those might be curricula that are
tuned to particular ethnic or linguistic preferences, to women-only
instruction, and other themes of that sort. Everything might come
into play except instruction that is overtly religious in its
orientation because, although there would be strong segments in
many communities that seek more religiously oriented instruction,
those are explicitly forbidden to enter publicly funded schools,
say through the charter movement. And in our observation of conversion
charter schools, which had a former religious base, those schools
are bending over backward not to retain a religious orientation
in their instruction because that would result in the revocation
of the charter if that were discovered.
If this observation is correct,
how should we regard it? Is it generally a positive thing to have
a reform movement that appears to underscore traditional approaches
to instruction, and that appears not to support more professionally
oriented and progressive reforms such as academics and business
elites and others are pressing in our society. How do you regard
that as a policy outcome? Needless to say, opinions will differ
on that matter. It does depend on what kinds of teaching and learning
we want in our schools, and quite naturally there is a continued
debate in our society over those matters. There is a great debate
over reading. What kinds of reading instruction do we want in
our schools? It looks to us as though charter and choice schools
will represent one strain within, say, debates about the best
kind of reading instruction to employ for children. That, too,
we may want to talk a bit about.
A third observation focuses on
two competing ideas about school reform that are in play within
schools of choice. Again, the focus is on choice as a stimulus
for promising ideas to improve teaching and learning. These two
reform ideas might be roughly characterized as pre-planned versus
improvised approaches. That is to say, one line of thinking about
how to create better schools in our society is to create a powerful
design for the school of the future based on expert and other
opinions and then, in effect, franchise that design across many,
many schools. Bring together the best minds in the country and
create a powerful design for a school, and then spread that design
across schools. Of course, the prime example of that approach
would be the Edison Project of New School Development Corporation,
where pre-planned designs have been developed and then they are
to be implemented faithfully with high fidelity across many schools
that would in effect accept those. The other approach to reform
is to create a mechanism by which entrepreneurial visionaries
can start a very idiosyncratic school based on all kinds of ideas
and if they can attract teachers and parents and kids to those
schools that will produce a kind of engine for innovation. Typically,
the entrepreneurs who have started charter schools based on idiosyncratic
visions dont have all of their ideas worked out in advance.
So they have to be improvising their ideas as they go in the course
of trying to start up and develop new schools.
Now, what is interesting about
those two approaches from the perspectives of policy analysts
is: Which one of those is likely to produce the best results?
Within something like the charter school movement, both kinds
of reform are available. That is to say, under Michigans
charter law you can have Edison Schools that started up, but you
also have the opportunity for local entrepreneurs who have their
own vision of what is a good school, how to start a school, how
to attract students to it, and how to try to work that vision
out. We see both visions operating, and I think in terms of the
long term reform of American education trying to understand how
each of those two kinds of reform are working out will clearly
be one very important analytic task in the coming years and not
only in Michigan.
And, finally, a fourth point concerns
the questions of whether the ingredients that comprise successful
schools of choice might in fact be created in regular public schools.
That is to say, what is it about schools of choice, charter schools,
that make them more attractive, or more successful than regular
public schools? Some of those factors might more or less easily
be applied to regular public schools. Therefore, an important
consequence of choice and charter movements would be to identify
factors that the public schools could adopt, and I think of that
sort there are roughly three factors that are going to be important
to understand. They are these. School size. Its very clear
based on the national charter school study that charter schools
are smaller on average than regular public schools, and one powerful
criticism of course of American school making is we just got it
wrong in the 50s. We went after economies of scales and
produced schools that were too big. You cant have elementary
schools of 800 kids. You cant have high schools with 2,000
and 3,000 kids. They produce massive bureaucratic, alienated environments
for teachers and students alike. And one great structural advantage
of schools of choice is that they are going to get the scale right.
They are going to create small, intimate learning communities
that will appeal to teachers and to students, and that create
a structural circumstance that makes the possibility for an educational
community much easier. So size may be a critical factor, and its
what parents want. Well, if that is the case, then in theory at
least we could resize many, many public schools by going to something
like schools within schools, and its been done. So one structural
advantage of choice school is clearly size.
A second is autonomy. We know what
the criticisms are. In many districts, schools operate at the
bottom of an organizational hierarchy that is stifling, and hierarchy
does do two things simultaneously: suck resources up into central
offices and constrain the autonomy of individual schools. So one
kind of criticism about how systems have gone wrong in this country
is that theyve created massive and bureaucratic operations
that fail to support necessary autonomy at the school site level,
and charter schools have the advantage of avoiding that sort of
thing and those sorts of complications. But again, if that criticism
of the evolution of the public school system, particularly in
the cities, has some truth to it, its quite possible to
develop governance and structural reform that begins to correct
that problem.
Probably exhibit A along those
lines is Chicago. There is a decentralizing experiment underway
in Chicago in which authority is driven down to the individual
school level, and the power of a large centralized bureaucratic
operation has been decisively weakened. That could mark a trend
across many large school systems.
The third factor is strong value
communities within an individual school. How is it that a school
creates a strong community of value that unites students, parents
and teachers in a set of shared values. I think there are basically
four factors that underlie the creation of strong value communities
in schools. They are: selection, socialization, involvement and
exclusion. Thats how you do it. You select people on values,
you socialize in a particular setting to a set of values, you
create mechanisms of high involvement, and you exclude from those
settings those who prove not be compatible with your value system.
Now, how do charter schools operate
on those criteria? Well, they are prohibited by law from selecting.
They have to take who comes. They are able to socialize as regular
public schools are. They probably have an advantage around involvement
with the primary mechanism being parental contracts that many
charter schools are using to increase levels of parental involvement,
and I think they have somewhat more flexibility in utilizing exclusion.
That is to say, they can kick kids out and right now they can
kick kids out with somewhat fewer of the due process guarantees
that would allow regular public schools to kick kids out. It may
be that a charter school enjoys certain advantages to regular
public schools on this dimension of creating a strong value community.
But there , too, it might be possible to adopt certain policies
that make it a more explicit goal particularly as parents clearly
want such a school for their children.
Those are a set of questions and
observations at the level of teaching, learning and school community
that we advance for your thinking.
Gary Sykes
Another kind of question we are
pursuing in our work asks: Will the introduction of choice policy
affect what happens inside of schools and classrooms? That is,
would we believe that the nature of teaching and learning in schools
of choice and regular public schools might change as a result
of choice policy? Would choice be a stimulus around the nature
of instruction? Certainly, at least some of the arguments in favor
of choice have emphasized that that will happen, and I would just
make four observations on that issue.
The first is that proponents of
choice claim that it will stimulate innovation and the spread
of good ideas or popular ideas and practices through processes
of entrepreneurialism, competition and imitation. That seems to
be a plausible point to make, but wed refine it somewhat
based on our observations to date by asking not whether this happens,
but in relation to what kinds of innovations. Our hunch is: Certain
kinds but not others.
In particular, our speculative
point, our hypothesis, is that the kinds of innovations that choice
policy is likely to stimulate are those that may be added on to
the existing structure and functioning of schools together with
those that are likely to attract a constituency. Examples would
be, as you have heard, all-day kindergarten, sending lap tops
home with children, having parent contracts for involvement. That
is, various kinds of innovations that dont penetrate to
the core operation of teaching and learning, but instead in some
sense may be added on to or mixed into the way schools have always
functions. The kinds of innovations that choice appears unlikely
to stimulate are those that require deep changes in the nature
of instructional practice as such changes implicate teacher knowledge
and skill, new norms, roles, and structures within classroom,
the introduction of new instructional materials, whose use requires
and places skill demands on teachers. All of those kinds of changes
are unlikely, we think, to be stimulated by the introduction of
choice.
But I think what is interesting
about that observation is that it perfectly reflects the history
of school reform in this country. That is to say, exactly that
generalization has been made by historians concerning those reforms
that have lasted in changing the American school system over its
180-year existence. In that sense then, choice operates as a stimulus
for reform at the level of fundamental teaching and learning in
about the same way that most other efforts have operated whether
those be changes in the curriculum or efforts to decentralized
or involve parents or incorporate progressive ideas about instruction
into schools. The reforms that have lasted in the evolution of
the American school system having been those that have been easy
to add on and that have attracted a political constituency around
them. An example would be special education, where the parents
of special needs students constitute a powerful constituency for
a set of reforms aimed at increasing resources for special needs
children. Choice will be good at stimulating some developments
within the schools, but not others. How one evaluates the impact
of choice on curriculum and instruction depends a great deal on
what you believe needs to change for improvements in learning
to occur, and we can talk a little about that because that will
provoke argument.
The second observation concerns
the ideas that influence curriculum and instruction and the sources
of influence on those ideas. Within the choice movement, parent
and community preferences appear to play a more prominent role
than professional judgments, and given the documented split between
popular and professional views about education, and now I am thinking
particularly about the surveys the Public Agenda group has made
that have shown that there are deep divisions within our society
between public and professional views of schooling. It appears
that popular view are likely to more prominent in choice and charter
schools. Roughly this translates to a tendency in schools of choice
toward more traditional approaches to teaching and learning that
might be expressed concretely in such things as phonics-based
approaches to literacy, more traditional approaches to mathematics
rather than the avant garde NCTM mathematics standards, more traditional
approaches to the teaching science rather the so-called constructivist
approaches. That is to say, choice is likely to stimulate an instructional
regime in schools that is traditional because that accords more
closely to the preferences of parents and communities to what
they want to see going on in terms of teaching and learning in
classrooms.
At the same time, it also appears
that charters and choice give expanded scope for particular and
specialized approaches to instruction and to curriculum that are
culturally tuned to societal subgroups, that seek schools representing
their particular approaches. Those might be curricula that are
tuned to particular ethnic or linguistic preferences, to women-only
instruction, and other themes of that sort. Everything might come
into play except instruction that is overtly religious in its
orientation because, although there would be strong segments in
many communities that seek more religiously oriented instruction,
those are explicitly forbidden to enter publicly funded schools,
say through the charter movement. And in our observation of conversion
charter schools, which had a former religious base, those schools
are bending over backward not to retain a religious orientation
in their instruction because that would result in the revocation
of the charter if that were discovered.
If this observation is correct,
how should we regard it? Is it generally a positive thing to have
a reform movement that appears to underscore traditional approaches
to instruction, and that appears not to support more professionally
oriented and progressive reforms such as academics and business
elites and others are pressing in our society. How do you regard
that as a policy outcome? Needless to say, opinions will differ
on that matter. It does depend on what kinds of teaching and learning
we want in our schools, and quite naturally there is a continued
debate in our society over those matters. There is a great debate
over reading. What kinds of reading instruction do we want in
our schools? It looks to us as though charter and choice schools
will represent one strain within, say, debates about the best
kind of reading instruction to employ for children. That, too,
we may want to talk a bit about.
A third observation focuses on
two competing ideas about school reform that are in play within
schools of choice. Again, the focus is on choice as a stimulus
for promising ideas to improve teaching and learning. These two
reform ideas might be roughly characterized as pre-planned versus
improvised approaches. That is to say, one line of thinking about
how to create better schools in our society is to create a powerful
design for the school of the future based on expert and other
opinions and then, in effect, franchise that design across many,
many schools. Bring together the best minds in the country and
create a powerful design for a school, and then spread that design
across schools. Of course, the prime example of that approach
would be the Edison Project of New School Development Corporation,
where pre-planned designs have been developed and then they are
to be implemented faithfully with high fidelity across many schools
that would in effect accept those. The other approach to reform
is to create a mechanism by which entrepreneurial visionaries
can start a very idiosyncratic school based on all kinds of ideas
and if they can attract teachers and parents and kids to those
schools that will produce a kind of engine for innovation. Typically,
the entrepreneurs who have started charter schools based on idiosyncratic
visions dont have all of their ideas worked out in advance.
So they have to be improvising their ideas as they go in the course
of trying to start up and develop new schools.
Now, what is interesting about
those two approaches from the perspectives of policy analysts
is: Which one of those is likely to produce the best results?
Within something like the charter school movement, both kinds
of reform are available. That is to say, under Michigans
charter law you can have Edison Schools that started up, but you
also have the opportunity for local entrepreneurs who have their
own vision of what is a good school, how to start a school, how
to attract students to it, and how to try to work that vision
out. We see both visions operating, and I think in terms of the
long term reform of American education trying to understand how
each of those two kinds of reform are working out will clearly
be one very important analytic task in the coming years and not
only in Michigan.
And, finally, a fourth point concerns
the questions of whether the ingredients that comprise successful
schools of choice might in fact be created in regular public schools.
That is to say, what is it about schools of choice, charter schools,
that make them more attractive, or more successful than regular
public schools? Some of those factors might more or less easily
be applied to regular public schools. Therefore, an important
consequence of choice and charter movements would be to identify
factors that the public schools could adopt, and I think of that
sort there are roughly three factors that are going to be important
to understand. They are these. School size. Its very clear
based on the national charter school study that charter schools
are smaller on average than regular public schools, and one powerful
criticism of course of American school making is we just got it
wrong in the 50s. We went after economies of scales and
produced schools that were too big. You cant have elementary
schools of 800 kids. You cant have high schools with 2,000
and 3,000 kids. They produce massive bureaucratic, alienated environments
for teachers and students alike. And one great structural advantage
of schools of choice is that they are going to get the scale right.
They are going to create small, intimate learning communities
that will appeal to teachers and to students, and that create
a structural circumstance that makes the possibility for an educational
community much easier. So size may be a critical factor, and its
what parents want. Well, if that is the case, then in theory at
least we could resize many, many public schools by going to something
like schools within schools, and its been done. So one structural
advantage of choice school is clearly size.
A second is autonomy. We know what
the criticisms are. In many districts, schools operate at the
bottom of an organizational hierarchy that is stifling, and hierarchy
does do two things simultaneously: suck resources up into central
offices and constrain the autonomy of individual schools. So one
kind of criticism about how systems have gone wrong in this country
is that theyve created massive and bureaucratic operations
that fail to support necessary autonomy at the school site level,
and charter schools have the advantage of avoiding that sort of
thing and those sorts of complications. But again, if that criticism
of the evolution of the public school system, particularly in
the cities, has some truth to it, its quite possible to
develop governance and structural reform that begins to correct
that problem.
Probably exhibit A along those
lines is Chicago. There is a decentralizing experiment underway
in Chicago in which authority is driven down to the individual
school level, and the power of a large centralized bureaucratic
operation has been decisively weakened. That could mark a trend
across many large school systems.
The third factor is strong value
communities within an individual school. How is it that a school
creates a strong community of value that unites students, parents
and teachers in a set of shared values. I think there are basically
four factors that underlie the creation of strong value communities
in schools. They are: selection, socialization, involvement and
exclusion. Thats how you do it. You select people on values,
you socialize in a particular setting to a set of values, you
create mechanisms of high involvement, and you exclude from those
settings those who prove not be compatible with your value system.
Now, how do charter schools operate
on those criteria? Well, they are prohibited by law from selecting.
They have to take who comes. They are able to socialize as regular
public schools are. They probably have an advantage around involvement
with the primary mechanism being parental contracts that many
charter schools are using to increase levels of parental involvement,
and I think they have somewhat more flexibility in utilizing exclusion.
That is to say, they can kick kids out and right now they can
kick kids out with somewhat fewer of the due process guarantees
that would allow regular public schools to kick kids out. It may
be that a charter school enjoys certain advantages to regular
public schools on this dimension of creating a strong value community.
But there , too, it might be possible to adopt certain policies
that make it a more explicit goal particularly as parents clearly
want such a school for their children.
Those are a set of questions and
observations at the level of teaching, learning and school community
that we advance for your thinking.